Money is Common Sense Part I: Definitions

Money is common sense. Anyone who tells you differently is a huckster or has been fooled by a huckster. Nevertheless, it takes a little consideration. For starters, it might be good to begin with a few questions such as:

  • What is money?
  • Does the value of money exist in its utilitarian economic benefits, or must money have intrinsic value?

There is an abyss quite close to my home. It best viewed, like the Grand Canyon, by a slow walk along its edges. Those of you that know this discussion extremely well, please don’t spoil the view by asking us to sprint from thought to thought. Instead, please walk with us, enjoying the relaxed pace of this peripatetic exercise with its gradual increments. Today we’ll see but the distant ridges of the abyss near my home, but we should be able to see them quite clearly.

  • Commodity currencies require no government involvement.
  • The value of an efficient currency far exceeds its value as a commodity.
  • As soon as Caesar’s image is on the currency, it becomes a fiat currency, a promissory note. Its represented commodity value will deflate, prices will inflate, and Caesar takes his cut.

The Primary Value of Money

Perhaps the freest economic form of exchange is the barter system. Imagine trading three lambs for a year’s supply of seed corn, or a pig for a measure of firewood for the winter. No money is used. The exchange requires no government agency or regulation, and the price was determined by the purest movement of supply and demand. Moreover, such an exchange is beyond taxation since the government is excluded entirely (That is not to say that some ancient publican would not have found a way to assess a tax on the land or livestock before the exchange).

Likewise, consider a primeval farmer’s market in which all the goods and produce were on display. Such a place might easily attract tradesmen with their wares. Garments of woven wool are bartered for the fleece of that years sheep. Primitive iron works are traded for bushels of grain. Money would be not necessarily be required at all. Instead, every good, service, or product could be exchanged with the immediacy of supply and demand. Or would they? Finding the precise deal would take effort. It is reasonable to assume that every deal for a desired commodity would include and exchange for other unwanted items. Suppose you wanted to trade a mule, but the best buyer had only asparagus with which to barter?

Enter the ability to barter with gold. One can vary purchases and exchanges tempering each more precisely to one’s need. Gold was easy to carry and desired by all for use in making glistening gods to adorn one’s home and garden. This universally accepted medium of exchange adds efficiency to the market. Now the laws of supply and demand can work more exactly. There are far fewer odd combinations of one merchant’s carrots and another’s ducks to hit on the correct exchange rate for the man trading in saddles.

From this model comes an example of the primary value of money: economy and efficiency in exchange. In an agrarian society this efficiency might be measured in man hours; in an industrial society the utilitarian value of money to the economy is inestimable. While it is a function of its value in the agrarian model, the utilitarian value of money increases exponentially as societies specialize and develop industry.

Now enter the gold coin. It’s even easier to measure, even easier to carry, and is still desired by all for use in making their glistening gods to adorn their homes and gardens. The laws of supply and demand work much more exactly. Specialization increases and with it quality and abundance. There are far fewer odd combinations of one merchant’s carrots and another’s ducks to hit on the correct exchange rate for the man trading in saddles.

It’s not until there is a coin of the realm that people start calling a commodity currency “money.” Whether there is a king, a Caesar, or a wealthy man who produces the coin, the coin changes economic realities significantly. The benefits of the coin is, first and foremost, confidence. Despite their being a seemingly inexhaustible demand for gold, or tobacco, or whatever the commodity currency might be, that commodity is of different value to each individual. The advent of the coin standardizes the value of the means of exchange to a significant extent. This added efficiency is worth it’s weight in gold. Well, actually, the increased market efficiencies are worth far more that the commodity value of the currency itself.

The Intrinsic Value of Money and the Money Supply

Of old, gold, silver, and copper each had an intrinsic value that assured their utilitarian value in facilitating the exchange of goods. This intrinsic value was based on supply and demand. If gold was scarce, then it would purchase more bushels of wheat. If silver was in great supply, it might purchase fewer chickens. In either case, the intrinsic value of money was determined by supply and demand relative to the supply and demand of the goods for which it facilitated exchange. The intrinsic value of the medium of exchange, the money itself, is never absolute. It also is subject to supply and demand.

Notice that when money has intrinsic value the money supply expands and contracts organically. No monetary policy is necessary.

Biblical Money

Work is as much a part of living as is breathing, and human labor is naturally most profitable under conditions of specialization and market efficiency. Unlike human labor, debt, lending, and living by usury are not part of a biblical economy and they are not, of themselves, beneficial to society. Debt, lending, and living by usury are kinks in the hose, donkeys in the well, and cracks in the cistern of a society’s prosperity.

The practice of usury is frowned on in the Bible. All debts were forgiven, or should have been forgiven, every seven years. Every seven years the land, or the essential means of production, reverted even to the most failed capitalist in Israel. These ethical premises also allowed for national prosperity to be renewed and financial blessings to flow freely. Even today, a bankruptcy is scrubbed from one’s credit rating after seven years.

There is, however, one record of successful creditors in the Bible. This is Matthew 25’s Parable of the Talents. The unfaithful steward hides his talent while the faithful stewards lend or invest their talents and repay their master with interest. What is important is that the faithful stewards put the actual weight of their money to work. They did not write promissory notes using the talent as a fractional reserve.

Once the discussion of money enters into the calculus of usury and debt, the subject becomes a house of cards. Monetary Policy and related definitions increasingly become a shell game more vicious than anything on the streets of the South Bronx. For the immediate future though, you need only watch you toes. Well only be playing with the sand sharks.

Keeping it simple, then, when a commodity currency is the sole currency, only bankers and those who take loans can wreck the simplicity and prosperity that comes to those who work when they can exchange their goods and services freely.

That pit in front of my house is that once a commodity currency becomes money, governments begin to affect monetary policy. Often, because they are governments, they affect the economy so irresponsibly that they bring down their own houses as well as the society upon which they’ve leached. At other times, governments ‘responsibly’ cull hidden taxes by keeping the rate of inflation at fixed levels. It’s still monetary slavery.

When Money has no Intrinsic Value

Such a thing is almost unimaginable at first blush. However, consider this model. The state, by taxation, and lets say, as in ancient Egypt under Joseph, by way of a miraculous windfall, owns tremendous amounts of goods and, by fiat or command, provides tremendous quantities of labor. Now, if the government issues an intrinsically valueless currency, it has the economic wherewithal to guarantee delivery of goods and services according to the contract the valueless currency has promised. All legal tender becomes a note of promise based on the financial wherewithal of the government to make good. This, of course, is where the United States currency must currently be categorized.

Historically, it has been the case that certain lending practices have also produced a variety of intrinsically valueless currencies. The bank offers a promise for the delivery of goods and services, and the promise itself becomes the basis of exchange. As long as the promise remains in circulation as a means of exchange, the goods promised by the bank (often a hard currency of intrinsic value) never gets delivered. It never gets delivered because the utilitarian value of the promise is of greater value than the intrinsic value of the promised goods or currency. When this balance of value changes, bank runs happened. Banks would go belly up and people would lose all their money. Historically, when this happens, there is a negative impact on the economy beyond the immediate inability to exchange goods and services. Some economists euphemistically describe this negative impact as a contracting money supply.

This contraction of the money supply is the bust portion of the boom and bust cycle. While the boom and bust cycle often is laid at the feet of “capitalism,” the cycle is not the product of free markets, or property, or property rights. The boom and bust cycles, at least in United States history, have all been, primarily, the consequence of runaway usury and the practice of fractional lending1. If banks were permitted to loan only the actual gold in their vaults, rather than to promise gold on a fractional basis, the boom and bust cycles would not have occurred with such violence.

When money has no value

When money cannot be exchanged for any good or service it is no longer money. Hence, from a strictly tautological standpoint all money has value, however infinitesimal.

Consider the inflation in the Weimar Republic between WWI and WWII. Although, certainly the Treaty of Versailles exacerbated the disaster, the root of the problem was the 1914 decision to go to an intrinsically valueless currency. Money not only lost its value so that it could not be used in place of barter, its small positive value was accompanied by a secondary negative economic value. Its failure to work as a medium exchange destabilized the state, disrupting, to some extent, even the opportunity for barter. At a certain point, money without intrinsic value will have both an infinitesimal microeconomic utilitarian value while having an inestimably large negative macroeconomic value.

This is enough for immediate consideration. Can you see that distant ridge on the far side of the abyss? It’s beautiful in its symmetry, is it not?

Corollary questions arise:

  • How like our semi-fictional example of Joseph’s Egypt is the U.S.economy?
  • What of a government able to procure goods and services enough to insure most of the promises of its valueless currency based on international debt?
  • Who should abhor an intrinsically valueless currency more, the political elites or the common man?
  • Can a debtor nation that owes its debt in an intrinsically valueless currency transition to an intrinsically valuable currency? What would be the effects?
  • If it can make a transition to a currency with intrinsic value, how should that value be chosen?

How can a bank lend me money it does not have, that I must repay by the sweat of my brow? (Indeed, if I repay only two or three times the amount the bank didn’t have to lend me, then I count myself fortunate and prosperous!) What is the name of this miracle of human stupidity? Answer: trolianfc nelngid

1. From Random History’s fairly standard A History of the U.S. Economy: Depressions (or Panics) of 1873 and 1893 were actually caused in large part by unrestrained development and financial over-speculation, … The Panics devastated small businesses.

… While the precise causes of the Great Depression are both numerous and challenging to pinpoint, the economic effects were disastrous. At its peak, unemployment was nearly 25 percent of the workforce as hundreds of banks failed (about 40 percent) and hundreds of millions of deposits were lost (Ferguson 2008).

And from Real Clear Markets on the panic of 1921: The storm broke in May of 1920 and arrived as these things usually do – almost everyone at the opera was caught napping when the lights suddenly came on. Bank failures, which numbered 63 in 1919, spiked to 506 by 1921. By June of the latter year, the money supply had dropped 9%, GNP 17%, and the index of wholesale prices collapsed from 247 in May of 1920 to 141 by July of 1921

2. Again from Random History: The 1917 War Revenue Act raised taxes while the government sold bonds to the general public and the newly founded Federal Reserve. … Taxes were lowered after the war, but remained higher than before it. The Federal Reserve assumed a more dominant role as New York became the financial center of the world. The federal government, in short, showed it could be a dominant force in the American economy. Notice the increased monetary power of the federal government after the institution of the Federal Reserve Banking system and the income tax.

Leave a Reply